22 marzo 2013

21 marzo 2013 mercado inmobiliario tiene más caída...

Más sobre mercado inmobiliario:

1) That, during the - ongoing - bust, Spanish home prices will fall to the level they were at when the boom began (a drop of 55%), and then stop falling right there.

2) That there is a bottom underneath prices, determined by their "utility value", i.e. people will always need to live somewhere.

As for 1), it immediately makes me think of a series of 3 graphs we use in Nicole's presentations, and which those of you who have acquired our DVD set "A World of Change" will readily recognize:

What you see is that in these 3 crises, the end point is (way) below the starting point, due to what can be called the "undershoot". In each case, it makes prices fall by well over 90% of its peak level. Now, Dave says he thinks homes are not tulips,

and so 2) the utility value of a house will make sure prices won't fall below the point their boom started. Not only do I find this too arbitrary an assumption (though, granted, in Dave's view he derives it from his data), there are a few other things that I feel may well influence this. That is, Spain built a huge amount of homes (more than Germany, France and Britain combined for 10 years), of which many are of too poor a quality to last for more than 20 years.

Moreover, something is true in Spain as it is all over the west: compared with 50 or 100 years ago, we occupy far more square meters per capita. That means there's a potential elasticity in that if prices remain too high, people will - forcibly - move (back) in together with family. Because we can. Demand is not what we want, but what we can afford. Seeing that youth unemployment in Spain presently stands at some 60%, you really need to wonder who's going to buy any homes there at all in the near future, and hence what bottom is supposed to apply to this housing market. It's tempting to think things must normalize at some point, but Spain has a crisis that extends far beyond housing.

I think we too easily overlook the potential for self-reinforcing, positive feedback across an economy. If Spain were to recognize the full 55% price drop, that would be the end of a large part of its banking system. And that in turn, for instance, would drive prices further down.

If the government in Madrid were more pro-active in restructuring the debts its banks hold, we would at least have a more accurate picture, but Spain does as the rest of Europe does: hide the debt behind more debt. The $25 billion loss announced by government-owned Bankia this week is a sign of what's going on behind the curtain, but no more than that.

Here's Dave and his data:


Dave Fairtex:

It is relatively well known that Spain has issues with their banking system, and that there was a property bubble and it popped several years ago. Various estimates have been floated as to how much it will cost to resolve the problem. But determining cost is not the only interesting question.

We want to be able to answer four questions:

• How much will it cost to resolve the problem?

• How long will it take to "return to normal"?

• How will we know when "normal" has been reached?

• What effects might this process have on spanish society?

The Bubble

It has been said that during a bubble pop, pricing always returns to its place of origin. This makes sense, as the prices one pays for something, once bubble psychology is removed from the equation, is tied to the actual utility received from having the item. That level is most likely the point at which prices diverged from the norm.

So, the first step in determining the cost involves identifying the point of origin of the bubble. Viewing a Spanish property price chart, one might argue that Spain's bubble started in approximately 2002. The start date is a relatively arbitrary designation - I picked a date when the trend of property price increases started to become particularly steep.

[Instead of using nominal prices for homes, I considered using real prices - i.e. prices deflated by the CPI. Then I concluded that the inflation that occurred on the way up would most likely be balanced by deflation on the way down. I am not sure this is true, but its one of the assumptions I made.]

So where are we now? Doing some quick math on this index provided by the Spanish Ministerio de la Vivienda it appears that home prices are down 27% from peak. However, anecdotal evidence from 2012 suggests property prices are closer to 35-40% below peak, and recoveries from foreclosure sales by a Spanish bank in 2012 show a 53% recovery rate - a 47% drop.

So let's say the preceding chart is not telling us the truth or if we're kind, we can say it lags substantially behind realtime. Likely instead of 73, it should probably be reading around 60. Operating under the assumption that prices will eventually return to around 45, that says prices are going to be off around 55% from peak when all is said and done. From a property pricing standpoint, we have another 33% left to go (60 to 45 = 33% drop from here). Perhaps the real price correction will end somewhere in mid 2014.

Resolution Cost

In looking at a property bubble, both the gains AND the losses are not confined simply to the homeowner and the mortgage lender. Developers, architects, builders, laborers, and bankers all benefit during the bubble years and suffer after the pop. Yet to examine effects only to those directly affected understates the the multiplying effect on income that the bubble provides. Each beneficiary buys things from other areas of the economy using consumer credit, takes out mortgage loans, companies takes on corporate debt to expand business, materials are extracted and shipped - all based on the phantom income derived from mortgage-bubble created money.

In order to come up with an amount to approximate first the gains, and then the losses due to the bubble, I decided on a simple approach - to use the amount of outstanding bank loans during the bubble years as a proxy for the overall impact of economic activity from the bubble, under the theory that credit money expands as economic activity expands.

In Ireland, where according to my estimates about €440 billion of "bubble loan money" was created, the government eventually spent €143 billion to rescue their banks and buy up (and overpay for) bad loans. So that €143 billion comes to 32% of the total bubble money created. It is entirely possible costs will rise in Ireland, but this number gives us a starting point for the explicit costs to the sovereign.

Totaling the bank loans made in the private sector, Spain created about €1.44 trillion in new bank credit during their bubble phase. [note: ECB data only goes back to 2003, so I had to estimate the amount bubble money created in 2002 to be about €100 billion.] If we assume the ratio of costs will be similar to that of Ireland, 32% of €1.44 trillion ends up being €460 billion - half for capital injections, and half for the Bad Bank.

To date, Spain has allocated €32 billion to their Bad Bank [Banco Malo] and an as of yet undetermined amount to their bank rescue/capital injection program. To put it mildly, this doesn't seem like nearly enough.

But is €460 billion the right amount? That's open to debate. It might be more.

A recent corruption scandal in Spain has resulted in PM Rajoy's popularity dropping - a recent survey had 85% of those polled having "little or no faith" in him. His party (the PP) had a 24% support rating, the lowest on record.

Why talk about corruption in a finance discussion? Well, corruption matters a great deal in these affairs - the managers of a Bad Bank have a lot of money to spread around, well-connected bankers have a whole lot of garbage assets they'd love to get rid of for as high a price as possible (and in fact their jobs DEPEND on them selling their garbage for as high a price as possible), and so the risk of overpayment for bad assets increases right along with the level of corruption. The more public money that gets dropped on the banks, the better condition the banks will be in - for paying salaries, bonuses, dividends, and so on, and the smaller the losses will be for bank shareholders and bondholders.

I assert that corruption is likely to raise the cost of the bailout, since the amount of public money that will be funneled to the bank will be maximized in a corrupt regime. I don't think the cost will be any lower than €460 billion, and Rajoy himself once mentioned the figure €500 billion as being required for a complete bank rescue. I do not think that was a number idly constructed from thin air. What's more, I believe that the folks at the Spanish Central Bank and the ECB are not fools. They've done the same math that I have, and Rajoy's remark was simply a political shot across the bows of the ECB in the negotiations over who pays what; a form of "don't mess with me or else the game is up."

It reminds me of the old saw - owe the bank 1000 dollars, the bank owns you. Owe the bank a billion dollars, and you own the bank!

That's all just speculation on my part, but I find it interesting that my math adds up to approximately Rajoy's threat. It wasn't intentional, but that's what came up.

So I believe that €500 billion is a good guess.

How long to return to normal?

The property bubble is over from the standpoint of pricing when property prices return back to their point of origin. (Its quite possible prices will overshoot as well, but lets leave that out of the discussion for now). It would seem that this might complete within the next year or two.

However calculating when the economy will "return to normal" is another matter entirely. Monetary deflation from the bubble sometimes continues long after prices have retraced. This is for several reasons, all of which have to do with the speed at which losses are recognized, as well as the level of debt forgiveness in the economy in question.

Hyman Minsky had a model where he attempted to explain the anatomy of a bubble through finance. In his model, there were three types of borrowers:

• Hedge Borrowers, whose debt repayments (principal, interest, taxes, expenses, etc) could be covered by the economic activity provided by the investment.

• Speculative Borrowers, whose investments could only cover the interest payments, and relied upon capital appreciation (bubble effects) to make up the difference.

• Ponzi Borrowers, whose investments could not even cover interest payments, and relied entirely on capital appreciation for the loan to make economic sense. Many of the subprime/neg-am borrowers fell into this last category.

The first phase of a pop involves rapid deflation, as corporations and finance organizations who were Ponzi and Speculative borrowers and who may legally walk away from their loan obligations do so relatively rapidly - taking perhaps 2-4 years. From the Ireland bubble charts, it seems that corporations bail out faster than the finance borrowers. Of course this depends on the willingness of the banking system to recognize the losses. "Extend and pretend" strategies drag this process out.

[Note: above chart is an attempt to show the "bubble loans" rather than the total bank loans for the period in question, in order to better compare the different sectors and how much money was created (borrowed) by each one relative to the others]

Losses tend to be the highest for these two types of borrowers; they are the least able to pay, have no money down, and have collateral whose value is entirely based on the former trajectory of bubble pricing. And they can legally walk away. And historically, they do.

Bad Banks tend to buy mostly these sorts of loans, and they have recovery rates that are much lower than those from foreclosed homeowner properties. You can see why - dubious assets such as unbuilt land bought with borrowed money at the top of the bubble is unlikely to have much value once the bubble pops.

The second phase involves hedge borrowers who can actually make the payments but do not want to lose the overvalued asset. By law and custom, regular people are much less willing to simply walk away from an investment gone bad. And in the case of both Spain and Ireland, full recourse laws require a homeowner to continue to make payments regardless of how underwater the homeowner is.

This second phase is also intrinsically deflationary, although the pace of deflation is much slower. In the credit model, money is created when a loan is taken out, and money is destroyed slowly as the loan is gradually paid back or rapidly when the loan is defaulted upon.

After a bubble pop, underwater homeowners are stuck until they pay down enough debt to restore their equity position. This act of slow debt paydown slowly destroys credit money, causing steady monetary deflationary pressure throughout this second phase. Although I have not done the research necessary to back this up, it is my speculation this is what caused the "lost decade" (or two) in Japan - the slow but steady monetary deflationary pressure from gradual debt paydown.

In Ireland, it has been estimated that underwater homeowners will need until 2020 for the bulk of them to get out of negative equity situations - and that is for those who put 20% down. For those who put 0% down and who by law cannot walk away, they will be at it until 2025. This is how long mild deflationary pressures will likely last in Ireland, assuming no changes to the law. In this, Spain is likely to follow Ireland.

The first deflationary phase is steep, lasting perhaps 3-4 years, while the second phase is more shallow and lasts from 8-14 years following, depending on the size of the bubble, as stuck homeowners and corporate hedge borrowers rebuild their equity positions by gradually paying down debt.

Estimating timeline for return to normalcy

We make an assumption that in addition to prices, all the outstanding bank loans that were based on bubble activity will also retrace back to its original starting position - back when the debt was sustainable and justified by steady-state economic activity. As all that unsustainable debt gets defaulted on or paid back, it will vanish.

Graphically, we can track where things are by looking at the outstanding amount of bank loans. In Spain, it is at €1.89 trillion, down from €2.26 trillion at the peak, but it needs to return to about €800 billion before the deflation has run its course. In Spain, it would appear that the first corporate deflationary impulse is in the process of happening now, although it would appear that the Spanish banks have been slow to acknowledge the losses. Based on the Irish experience, it probably has another 2 years to run, assuming the banks are actually required to take their losses.

In some sense this is a moral tale. Corporations get (debt) forgiveness, but in Spain and Ireland regular people don't. This lack of (debt) forgiveness is why the second phase of a deflationary bubble pop will last a long time: it takes people a long time to pay down all that debt. So forgiveness, in addition to it being a Christian virtue, allows things to return to normal more rapidly.

So where are we in Spain? It is just starting to happen seriously, 5 years after the peak in prices. And without changes in the law, it's going to last a very long time.

By Raul Ilargi Meijer

Abrazos,

PD1: ¿Cuál es el valor real de los inmuebles? No se sabe, todo está subsidiado, todo está estimulado con QE…, pero no se puede mantener en el tiempo estos paquetes de estímulo económico…:

"Los precios de los bonos, acciones, oro e inmuebles están subsidiados"

 

Druckenmiller detalla que a finales de 2004, o principios de 2005 descubrió que la estructura demográfica norteamericana de la población era una auténtica "tormenta que se avecinaba". Incluso explica cómo se reunió con varios congresistas para convencerles de que debían afrontarla en los siguientes años, pero no le hicieron caso. Según él, estamos en la primera fase de la burbuja demográfica que amenaza seriamente a los Estados Unidos. Solo recordaros que la estructura demográfica europea y japonesa son mucho peores que la norteamericana. En el continente europeo los mayores riesgos están en Alemania, Grecia, España y, especialmente, Portugal (ver el post del impacto demográfico en el precio futura de la vivienda). Ya lo alertó también McCoy en 2010 para los países europeos.

En los últimos 10 años, Druckenmiller relata que los gastos en los sistemas públicos de sanidad en USA, como el Medicare y el Medicaid, así como los gastos de la Seguridad Social han crecido a un ritmo imparable, y no por el efecto demográfico, que aún está por venir, sino por la presión social. Según él, los jubilados actuales están robando a los jubilados futuros.

En relación a la actuación de los bancos centrales, Druckenmiller critica a Greenspanpor provocar la gran burbuja inmobiliaria tras las inyecciones artificiales después de la crisis de las empresas tecnológicas a principios del 2000. En lugar de aceptar una recesión lógica, Greenspan decidió alterar artificialmente la economía con tipos de interés muy bajos en un entorno de crecimiento económico. También cree que "Bernanke no parará esta política de la Fed. Los bancos centrales continuarán imprimiendo más tiempo del que pensamos".

Según Stanley, "Excepto Brasil, todo el resto de bancos centrales aplican las mismas políticas extremadamente expansivas a la vez".

"Cuando leo que muchos opinan que las acciones están mas baratas que los bonos, pienso que si que es cierto, pero en realidad todos los activos están mas baratos que los bonos. Todos los activos están subsidiados, no solo los bonos, también las acciones, el oro y los inmuebles".

Y hablando sobre Draghi, explica cómo ha creado un "gran paraguas protector en los activos en euros".

Sobre su opinión acerca de la bolsa actual, Druckenmiller afirma que la bolsa parece barata a los precios actuales, pero si normalizas los beneficios empresariales y la demanda de la economía norteamericana, ya que hoy tiene un déficit público del 9%, la bolsa no está tan barata como parece.

Finalmente, alerta de que toda esta fiesta "acabará sin duda y, además, acabará mal, aunque no se si será el próximo mes, el próximo año, en cinco o incluso en 10 años".

PD2: Las previsiones son que se está claudicando en materia de precio. Quien quiere vender, tiene prisa por vender. Tiene esa sensación de que esto sigue bajando y que las visitas son de fisgue y sólo se cruzan operaciones con grandes descuentos. Y el que compra sólo lo hace si tiene cash, no hay crédito hipotecario, y sólo compra si el vendedor acepta una nueva rebaja o quita…

La caída de la vivienda se acelerará en los próximos meses, según idealista.com

El jefe de estudios de idealista.com, Fernando Encinar, ha asegurado que la tendencia bajista de los precios de la venta de inmuebles se acelerará en los próximos meses empujada por la contracción del crédito y la incertidumbre del mercado laboral.

En un comunicado, idealista.com recomienda a los propietarios que tengan una "oferta en firme" que la acepten, ya que la bajada "histórica" de los precios en 2012 (13,7%) demuestra que sólo los propietarios que realizaron bajadas "agresivas" consiguieron vender sus inmuebles.

De hecho, asegura que aquellos que se resistieron a aplicar descuentos en sus viviendas no lograron cerrar las operaciones y ahora se van a ver obligados a rebajar aún más sus expectativas.

PD3: En Madrid todo el mundo quiere vender su plaza de parking y los precios de los garajes caen… No hay dinero para nada, ni para pagar donde guardar el coche. Se deja en la calle y si hay que dar vueltas se dan, o se va en transporte público…

PD4: Parece ser que se han cabreado… Now Oligarchs and just "Russians" will transfer their funds out of Cyprus, Spain & Latvia (pls no high expectations here) into Switzerland!

Si salen del euro, como amenazan, el BCE podría quebrar!!! Y ser la espoleta de una ruptura del euro, por su efecto dominó…

Cyprus's Four Options to Avoid Banking Collapse

Las consecuencias están aquí: las elecciones de Alemania. ¡Ay!: Germany - Forsa poll: CDU/CSU 40%, SPD 24%, Greens 15%, Left 7%, FDP 6%, Pirates 3%

PD5: NYC: La unión de miles y miles de fotos de altísima calidad, imposible de lograr con las cámaras de vídeo. Impresionante. ¿Quieres pasar un día en Nueva York?

PD6: ¿Y si España aplica también una tasa a los depósitos para rescatar autonomías? Tiene guasa que Montoro anuncie un impuesto sobre los depósitos el día que Chipre rechaza su particular tasa. Vaya Gobierno que tenemos... Cuando nos van arañando poquito a poquito parece otra cosa…

- Resulta que ZP ya me robó un 5 % del sueldo.

- Rajoy me chorizó una paga extra.

- El gobierno autonómico me quita ahora otro 5 %.

- Me han subido el IVA y el IRPF.

- El banco me mantiene el suelo a la hipoteca, y me cobra comisiones que rayan la usura.

- Y menos mal que no me han pillado en una preferente…

Lo mejor que me podía haber pasado es que me hubieran quitado un 6.75% de mis depósitos!!!!

PD7: Me entra la risa floja: De Guindos: "En España y la UE son sagrados los depósitos inferiores a 100.000 euros". Estoy convencido de que el entuerto europeo se soluciona con más gasto publico financiado con más deuda bancaria

Dice Bloomberg que el tipo medio que pagan los bancos de Chipre por sus depósitos es el 4.5% y lo compara con el 1.5% que pagan en Alemania. Lo de siempre, duros a cuatro pesetas que al final provoca que se pierde la pasta… (preferentes, Bankia, Rumasa…)

Dedicado a tanto europeo que ve "imposible" cerrar/quebrar de bancos. Lista de bancos cerrados USA, más de 300 desde 2008!!!

La banca aún necesita 224.200 millones para alcanzar la solvencia que requerirá Basilea III: http://www.expansion.com/2013/03/19/empresas/banca/1363688586.html

PD8: ¿Por qué no baja la bolsa? Porque no hay muchas alternativas rentables. La gente huye de los depósitos bancarios y los bonos están en rentabilidades muy bajas. No hay más cáscaras que quien quiera rendimiento se la tiene que jugar. Igual que se la juegan con su banco sin saber si en unos fines de semana nos tocará lo mismo que Chipre o no, se la juegan con la bolsa ya que es donde más expectativas hay…:

¿Qué es lo que está sosteniendo a la bolsa?

Más que la mejora de los fundamentales macroeconómicos, J.P.Morgan AM cree que lo que está impulsando a la renta variable es su potencial de rentabilidad adicional en comparación con los mercados de renta fija 'core' y de liquidez.

El favorable comportamiento mostrado por la bolsa está sorprendiendo a algunos inversores. ¿Qué factores estarían potenciando el buen comportamiento de las acciones? SegúnJ.P.Morgan Asset Management, "más que la mejora de los fundamentales macroeconómicos, lo que está sosteniendo a la renta variable es su potencial de rentabilidad adicional en comparación con los mercados de renta fija core y de liquidez. Dadas las fuertes ganancias de la renta variable en los últimos meses y teniendo en cuenta las perspectivas de bajo crecimiento de los beneficios corporativos en la mayoría de mercados desarrollados, se debería perdonar a los inversores por poner en duda la continuidad del reciente rally en los mercados de valores".

Esto no significa que la Bolsa esté en una fase en la que solo pueda subir. Según explica la firma estadounidense en su último informe Market Insights, "no podemos descartar ver a corto plazo cierto movimiento de toma de beneficios. Sin embargo, la rentabilidad real negativa ofrecida por los activos de renta fija gubernamental core y por cuentas corrientes limitan el atractivo de los activos tradicionales libres de riesgo en comparación con la renta variable, y salvo por algún shock macroeconómico o político, vemos pocos argumentos por los que los inversores debieran salirse de renta variable; sobre todo dado el atractivo de las valoraciones de renta variable global", afirman desde la entidad.

PD9: Fariseos…

Los fariseos eran esos que cumplían todo a la perfección, pero sin meter amor en sus rezos/actos… Se engañaban. Ojalá nunca seamos fariseos nosotros, que todo lo que hagamos sea siempre por amor, no por impresionar, no por aparentar, no por cumplir. Recuerdo las confirmaciones de mis numerosos hijos cuando el Obispo nos hablaba del cumplimiento, es decir, del "cumplo y miento", cumplir los preceptos, pero engañarnos a nosotros mismos. ¿A quién podríamos engañar, a Dios que todo lo sabe? No hombre por favor, nunca seamos fariseos. Si quieres ir a Misa vas; si no, no vas. Pero si vas es porque quieres ir, porque quieres ir a dar gracias a Dios, a pedirle algo, porque sabes que es tu obligación dominical, por lo que sea… Pero no se aceptan +mentiras. Dios nos dio toda la libertad del mundo para que, en materia religiosa, pudiéramos elegir, pudiéramos optar por un camino u otro. No engañamos a nadie, el Señor todo lo sabe, sabe de nuestras debilidades y perezas, de nuestros pecados, de nuestras miserias. No le podemos engañar nunca. Y eso lo sabemos todos. ¿Qué tal ha ido la Cuaresma? ¿Hiciste buenos propósitos que luego se quedaron en agua de borrajas? Mucho ánimo. En estos temas siempre es empezar y recomenzar…, volverlo a intentar, pedirle ayuda…, cada día es uno nuevo y se puede volver a intentar. Nadie nos castiga si no lo logramos, nadie nos lo echa en cara…, ánimo!